Class, Community and
Communicative Planning: Urban
Redevelopment at King’s Cross,
London
Ståle Holgersen and Håvard Haarstad
Department of Geography, University of Bergen, Fosswinckelsgate 6, Norway;
havard.haarstad@geog.uib.no
Abstract: This paper presents an argument for considering issues of class in analyses of
communicative planning projects. In these projects, class interests tend to be obscured by the
contemporary preoccupation with the class-ambiguous category of “community”. Through a
case study of a project of urban redevelopment at King’s Cross in London, we conceptualize and
map class interests in an urban redevelopment project. Three aspects of the planning process that
contain clear class effects are looked at: the amount of office space, the flexibility of plans, and
the appropriation of the urban environment as exchange or use value. These aspects structure the
urban redevelopment but are external to the communicative planning process. The opposition to
the redevelopment has in the planning discourse been articulated as “community”-based rather
than in class-sensitive terms. We finally present three strategies for reinserting issues of class
into planning theory and practice.
Keywords: communicative planning, class, antagonisms, community, London, King’s Cross
Introduction
The 67 acres of land at King’s Cross in London is the site of what has
been labeled the biggest inner city redevelopment in Europe. Its location
at the edge of the City of London and next to the end terminal for the
high-speed rail link from Paris and Brussels places this redevelopment
at the centre of strategies for maintaining London’s position as a
hub for global financial capital accumulation. Yet issues of class are
virtually absent from the discussions around the redevelopment, which
are managed through a “communicative” planning process and resisted
by various “community” groups. While business interests in the conflict
around the development have been articulated as such, opposition groups
have been included in the class-ambiguous category of “community”.
The ideal of communicative planning has been subject to criticism
from planning theorists who from various theoretical perspectives argue
that proper communication cannot overcome unequal power relations
and access to channels of influence. Less attention has been paid
Antipode Vol. 41 No. 2 2009 ISSN 0066-4812, pp 348–370
doi: 10.1111/j.1467-8330.2009.00676.x
C 2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
Urban Redevelopment at King’s Cross, London
349
to the mechanisms by which issues of class take part in structuring
power relationships in planning processes and the class effects of the
contemporary preoccupation with the notion of “community”.
This paper is an attempt to understand how issues of class and
economic antagonisms structure the planning process in King’s Cross.
Planning based on the communicative ideal mainly considers conflicts
that can be resolved through communication. Economic antagonisms,
lines of actual or potential conflict of economic interests, are based on
structural material processes in capitalist society that are less likely to be
overcome merely through proper communication. These processes are
often understood through a bipolar distinction between capital and labor,
the most abstract division between capitalist classes. In analyses of the
urban environment this distinction can be traced to Lefebvre, among
others. In order to concretize this distinction further we analyze agents
in the planning process in terms of functions and the class processes in
terms of layers.
We look at three aspects of the planning process that we argue
contain class effects: the amount of office space; flexibility in the plans;
and the appropriation of urban environment as exchange value or use
value. These aspects structured the planning process and constitute
economic struggles, but were not considered in the communicative
process. Further, we argue that the main agents in a planning process
can be mapped according to economic interests and functions. This
opens up an understanding of economic power relations and the class
effects of a particular planning project. By making visible economic
antagonisms that are not included in communicative processes, this
analysis is intended to encourage class-sensitive planning theory and
class-sensitive politics in planning practice.
The paper proceeds as follows. The next section outlines the
discussion on “the communicative turn” in planning theory and argues
that both its proponents and critics tend to downplay economic
antagonisms. The third section presents a framework for analyzing
class relations in an urban planning project, and the fourth section links
neoliberalism to the discourse of “community” in London. These are
followed by the empirical section, which analyzes the three abovementioned aspects of the planning process that have effects on class
relations. In the conclusion we return to the argument of inserting
class into planning theory and practice, and propose three strategies
for moving forward.
The Communicative Turn and its Critics
A number of urban planning theorists have brought attention to
the “communicative turn” in urban and regional planning theory
(Allmendinger and Tewdwr-Jones 2002; Amdam and Veggeland
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
350
Antipode
1998; Gunder 2003; Healey 1996; Yiftachel and Huxley 2000). The
“communicative turn” has arguably reached a certain consensus around
key theoretical and methodological questions (Yiftachel and Huxley
2000). This consensus is based on the communicative ideal (Skjeggedal
2005), and makes claims such as the need for normative theory, the
relevance of agency over structure and the interest in studying practice.
In the UK, this current has been referred to as “collaborative planning”
(Allmendinger and Tewdwr-Jones 2002). In Habermas’ (1993) intersubjective communicative rationality, participation and communication
form the basis for emancipation and social justice. The essence of
communicative planning is that through learning how to collaborate
and through successful communication it is possible to resolve conflicts
and obtain agreement and consensus (Healey 1999). It is important to
keep in mind that the ideal speech situation is just that, an ideal, and that
even Habermas conceded that most instances of communicative action
do not replicate this ideal (Allen 1986:15).
Significant theoretical criticism has emerged against the communicative ideal in urban planning. Habermas posited the ideal speech situation
as a criterion by which to register the “distorted communication”
inherent in most interactions, but as Fainstein (2000) argues, when
ideal speech instead becomes the objective of planning, the tendency
of economic forces to distort communication is downplayed. The
proponents of the communicative ideal “seem to forget the economic and
social forces that produce endemic social conflict and domination by the
powerful” (Fainstein 2000:455). Arguably, the communicative approach
in planning assumes that economic antagonisms can be overcome
through communicative action. Gunder (2003), Fainstein (2000) and
Flyvbjerg (1998) have noted the lack of understanding of power in
communicative planning. Although communicative planning accepts
certain social power relations as given, it is assumed that communication
can erase antagonisms and in turn that these antagonisms are embedded
in communicative processes rather than in material processes. It is
almost as “if only people were reasonable, deep structural conflict
would melt away” (Fainstein 2000:455). Attention is diverted from
the “underlying material and political processes which shape cities and
regions” (Yiftachel and Huxley 2000:907). Gunder (2003:308) argues
instead for a planning practice that should aim to plan “for the joy of
the Others’ desire”.
Flyvbjerg’s (1998) critique of the communicative ideal is based on the
notion that power relations are embedded in communication and sociocultural practices. That is, it focuses on the weaknesses in democratic
processes as a result of social, rather than economic, antagonisms.
The communicative process allows change “only as long as it does
not transcend the existing system” (Flyvbjerg and Petersen 1983:26).
He argues that by distinguishing between “successful” and “distorted”
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
Urban Redevelopment at King’s Cross, London
351
communication, the communicative ideal obscures the power relations
necessarily embedded in communication. But a danger of this otherwise
pertinent critique is that economic factors and their significance in
conditioning the geographical landscape of capitalism are downplayed
(Merrifield 1993:528). While discursive power relations embedded
in socio-cultural practices certainly are shaping planning processes,
we would like to bring attention (back) to the ways in which these
power relations and practices are grounded in material and economic
antagonisms.
Even when accepting communicative action as the ideal, there are
empirical and practical problems involved in shaping planning processes
democratically. For example, shaping these processes involves decisions
about the inclusion and exclusion of “stakeholders”, often determined
by practicalities. Mace argues, based on work in King’s Cross, London,
that when participation and “inclusion” is the aim, the “hard to reach”
become “harder to reach” (Mace 2007). Even in a rather smaller context,
with an example from the Norwegian municipality Sogndal with only
3000 inhabitants, Naustadalslid (1991) shows that a communicative
approach in planning produced “more power to the powerful”. When
the collaborative processes themselves are shaped and delimited by
institutions and agents with a particular agenda, there are limitations for
what participation can achieve.
In other words, economic relations form planning processes in important ways that tend to be downplayed in the focus on ideal communication. There is a need to address the question of how underlying
economic structures and class antagonisms structure the potential for
redistributive planning.
Conceptualizing Class in Urban Planning
Engaging a perspective on economic antagonisms involves identifying
economic interests in a planning process, in order to see the dialectics
between them. Our focus is on how the planning process is delimited and
shaped by these economic interests. Economic antagonisms are often
understood through a bipolar distinction between capital and labor, and
this distinction can also be found in analyses of the urban environment.
Edwards et al draw a bipolar distinction between these interests in
empiric research on London:
In rather oversimplified terms, one can say there have been those
interests which are concerned about the future of London as a viable
business environment and those interests which are concerned about
the future of London as a place to live (Edwards et al 1992:188–189).
Within the former, the “growth coalitions” are the business elites,
unions, media, academics and they “involve the co-option of local
authorities”. And the latter, the “citizen perspective”, is built up of
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
352
Antipode
“the variety of different groups in the population” (1992:188–189). In
Lefebvre (1973) and Smith (1991) we find the same bipolar distinction,
between those who relate to urban space in terms of use value versus
those who relate to the space as exchange value. Lefebvre articulated
this as a contradiction which contains a “clash between a consumption
of space which produces surplus value and one which produces only
enjoyment—and is therefore “unproductive”. It is a clash, in other
words, between capitalist “utilizers” and community “users” (Lefebvre
1991:359–360). We find this main distinction, with its numerous
exceptions and ambiguities, valuable in our project. These bipolar
antagonisms, which echo the abstract distinction between capital and
labor, are necessarily transformed into finer grade distinctions when
applied in empirical research. For example in King’s Cross, parts of
local capital interests allied with local activists and other stakeholder
groups, which makes bipolar distinctions difficult.
Class can be theorized in a variety of ways, also in a planning
process. Several kinds of capitalist class agents are present in the urban
development process. Harvey divides these into fractions of capitalist
classes and looks at how they relate to the built environment (Harvey
1978, 1985). In a concrete planning case it may be more productive
to analyze class agents through their function in an urban development
process. As Edwards argues, this is because particular agents or fractions
of “labor in general” (Harvey 1985) may be absent in a particular case,
“the main functions in urban development always have to be performed”
(Edwards 1995). In an analysis of a communicative planning process, a
sole focus on agents inhibits an understanding of how the positions
of different agents affect the structuring of the urban development
process. Since functions can be performed by a single agent or sets
of separate agents, focusing on functions emphasizes the importance of
organizational forms in an urban development process. It may also make
visible agents and functions that are necessary in the urban development
process but that might be hidden in the planning process. For example,
financiers may not participate in the planning process, but have a central
function in urban development.
Within a particular planning project there may be intra capital class
antagonisms or class alliances. Conflict might occur between local and
financial capital, with opposing interests in relation to the construction of
office space versus shopping areas, or between industrial and financial
capital over national policy, which later transforms urban geography
and social reality. Local capital may in turn form coalitions with
citizen groups that seek vibrant, multi-use communities, for example.
In addition, groups in antagonistic relations with capital interests may
not articulate themselves on the basis of work or economic production,
but for example on the basis of environmental questions that seem to
cut across the capital/labor distinction.
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
Urban Redevelopment at King’s Cross, London
353
As for the non-accumulating classes, these may be labeled labor in
general. Labor appropriates the built environment through consumption
and as a means to social reproduction (Harvey 1985). Labor is also
“sensitive to both the costs and the spatial disposition of the various
items in the built environment” (like housing, education, services of all
kinds and so on) (Harvey 1985:168). But again, finer-grade distinctions
are necessary in empirical research. Conceptual frameworks need to
capture both structural and economic antagonisms, and the way these
are articulated and contradicted in specific planning conflicts. As we aim
to show through the following case study, class interests are articulated
in multiple and contradictory ways, that significantly structure processes
of communicative planning.
One way of conceptualizing class interests while allowing for their
complexity in a specific communicative planning project is to see class
relations as existing on different layers. Katznelson’s (1993) distinction
between four different layers of class relations may serve as a point of
departure. Marx’s phrase that bourgeoisie is the embodiment of capital
(Marx 1990:92), or Harvey’s phrase that the commodity is the “material
embodiment of use-value, exchange-value and value” (Harvey 1999:1)
are important, but might be problematic if the abstract levels and their
embodiments are discussed at the same time or confused. Operating
within a conceptualization of class as simultaneously articulated on
different layers might help in organizing this complexity.
This distinction works as a methodological and theoretical tool for
conceptualizing economic antagonisms while allowing for these to be
articulated in empirical research. The first layer is within structures
of capitalist development, and related to the value of theory and the
methodology of abstraction. This is the layer where we find the structural
separation between capital and labor. The second layer is that of social
existence. This concerns how “actual people live within determinate
patterns of life and social relations” (Katznelson 1993:208), such as
their workplace or residential area. The third layer concerns how people
“come to represent their lived experiences and how they constitute a
normative guide to action”. The fourth layer concerns collective action;
the ways in which actors self-consciously decide (not) to organize to
benefit their perceived interests. The benefit of conceptualizing class
interests in a communicative planning process through layers is that it
opens up the possibility of researching antagonisms on one layer while
acknowledging that these may be connected with antagonisms on a
structural layer, or it might also help explain why antagonisms at one
layer do not necessarily lead to conflict at another layer.
By using these notions of functions and layers it is possible to
conceptualize collective action articulated through a communicative
planning process that may cut across abstract class interests, for example
when a community group composed of citizen and environmental
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
354
Antipode
activists and workers form coalitions with local capital owners—or
perhaps even financial capital. The antagonistic groups in the King’s
Cross development mostly cut across clear class categories. These
coalitions are articulations of the complex interests and stakeholders
within urban planning projects that do not always cater exclusively
to actually existing class interests. Instead, the articulation of the
conflicting groups in King’s Cross are in line with the contemporary
neoliberal emphasis on “community”.
Neoliberalism and the Discourse of Community in London
Recent neoliberal transformations in London have been well documented, and will not be subject to much discussion here. Various
accounts describe these, usually in bipolar terms, as changes from
“Fordism” to “neo-Fordism” (Knox and Pinch 2006), from “modernism
to postmodernism” (Harvey 1989), from “Keynesian cities” to “postFordist cities” (Short 1996:79), and from “embedded liberalism” to
“neoliberalism” (Harvey 2005). The city of London has been central
to these transformations, and changed from an “industrial” to a “postindustrial” city (Hamnett 2005). A dominant feature of these changes
for London has been the sedimentation of hegemony for financial capital
(Harvey 2005). The hegemonic shift from industrial to financial capital is
crucial to understanding developments in the planning policy of London.
This hegemony has been seen as part of a new class project driving social
change in global cities (Harvey 2005; Toulouse 1991).
These changes have impacted on political organizing strategies,
particularly for labor. Flexibility in labor relations is a central element of
the neoliberal policy regime and accounts of contemporary capitalism
(Jessop 1994; Lash and Urry 1987). Some of the responsibilities of the
national state have been distributed to multilateral and local institutions
that are typically less vulnerable to the organizing strategies of national
labor unions (Brenner 2004; Gibson-Graham 2006:46; Peck and Tickell
2003; Swyngedouw 2004). There seems to have been a shift in power
relations between employers and workers in which the former have been
emboldened by neoliberal policies that have given them the ability to
relocate geographically (Wills 2001). In short, the “structural context” of
collective political organization is changing (Cerny 1995:595; Haarstad
2007), and we will argue that this is manifested in that the opposition to
the planned development at King’s Cross is articulated as “community”
rather than “labor”.
New classes of migrant and temporary workers that have emerged in
cities such as London fall below the scope and strategies of traditional
labor unions, and “community unions” have in some cases tried to fill
this void (Fine 2005; May et al 2007). A disproportionate number of
London’s low-paid jobs are now filled by foreign-born workers, and the
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
Urban Redevelopment at King’s Cross, London
355
new “migrant division of labor” creates challenges for organization
(May et al 2007). Planning policy in London has promoted these
changes, as it has sought to strengthen the position of London as a
financial world city. The London Plan 2004 asserts that the fundamental
factor driving change in London’s employment structure during the last
30 years has been “the gain of 600,000 jobs in business services and
the loss of 600,000 jobs in manufacturing” (London Plan 2004:26). It
projects that the business service sector will make the most significant
contribution to economic growth in London over the next 15 years, with
440,000 further jobs, just over half of all new jobs created.
The attraction of financial capital was consolidated under Tony Blair,
as New Labour embraced neoliberalism with a friendly face. Jones and
Ward (2002:141) argue that New Labour’s urban white paper has a
“policy gene” and a content that are heavily reminiscent of the previous
urban white paper. New Labour promoted a somewhat contradictory
policy of, on the one side endorsing community-led initiatives (see
DETR 1998) and on the other, reorganizing the Department of Trade
and Industry with an aim to increase the voice of business in economic
policy formulation and implementation (Jones and Ward 2002). As
an expression of the contemporary preoccupation with the notion of
“community” in planning is the Statement of Community Involvement
(SCI) (ODPM 2004) that was introduced into the English planning
system. The SCI introduced a requirement that the Local Planning
Authority produce a policy statement on how they will engage with
communities in developing planning policy (Mace 2007). In turn,
both community involvement and the promotion of financial business
interests are central elements of contemporary planning discourses on
London. These discourses arguably obscure class conflicts, in particular
since the “community” category is ambiguous towards class identities.
It can be argued that this is in large part the reason that the notion of
“community” has integrated so well within neoliberal policy discourses.
The empirics for the analysis are based on fieldwork in London
between August and December 2006, including semi-structured
interviews with actors in the conflict, the collection of relevant
documents and reports and participant observation in various meetings.
The focus on class interests influenced the fieldwork by orienting
interviews towards interviewees with a range of class positions rather
than a random survey of opinions. The interviewees broadly represent
the main interests in the planning process.
King’s Cross Development and Economic Antagonisms
The terminal station for the Channel Tunnel Railway Link (CTRL) from
Paris and Brussels opened at the end of 2007 at St Pancras station in
London. King’s Cross Central is located in the London Borough of
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
356
Antipode
Camden, bordering the Borough of Islington. Among England’s top100 “most deprived wards” we find 24 out of Camden’s 26 wards and
the unemployment in Camden is at 7%, while the average in London
is 4% (Tewdwr-Jones, Morphet and Allmendinger 2006). According to
Camden’s Community Strategy from 2001, King’s Cross is one of these
deprived areas in the Borough (Camden 2001). But Camden is also a
polarized borough. According to Camden’s Community Strategy, “[the]
gap between the most and least deprived wards in Camden is bigger
than anywhere else in London” (Camden 2001:6).
The development of the terminal station for the Paris–London
Railway in King’s Cross has been a process spanning about two decades.
The London Regeneration Consortium submitted the first application
for planning permission to the Borough of Camden in 1989, also at that
time with a large amount of office space. In 1991 the Environmental
Commissioner instructed the King’s Cross development to halt because
of an inadequate Environmental Assessment. Organized resistance and
unwilling local politicians delayed the process on technical grounds until
the crash in the property market in 1992 made the project undesirable.
Alternatives for routes and terminals were evaluated in 1993, whereby St
Pancras and an overland connection from Stratford were favored. After
the property market recovered, the Channel Tunnel Rail Link Bill passed
in Parliament in 1995 for a largely tunneled route into the St Pancras
station. London and Continental Railways (LCR) won the competitive
bid. Instead of “normal” subsidies in return for building the rail, LCR
received fixed assets, ie railway stations, trains and land areas along
the route with the right to develop these for profit. In an article, The
Guardian (1 March 1996) called the deal “the great railway give-away”,
and estimated the total value of the subsidy at £5.7 billion.
The main local planning authority is Camden, and Camden is
obviously operating in a policy context where it is subordinated to the
Greater London Authority and the British state. According to LCR, the
development is the biggest ever single construction project in Britain,
and more than £9 billion will be invested in the areas adjacent to the
new stations (interview, media contact, LCR). The 67 acres of land that
this paper is concerned with, that is the King’s Cross Central, is one of
those areas of land received by LCR as a subsidy. The site at King’s
Cross is currently developed by an “ownership vehicle” owned in part by
LCR (35%), Exel (15%) and Argent (50%). Argent is the development
enterprise, receiving shares in the vehicle as payment. The 67 acres are
divided in two by a canal that goes from east to west. South of the canal
there will be mostly offices, and north of the canal will host housing, a
University of Arts, plazas, and a community house, among other things.
The development has been controversial locally. Various “community
groups” involved themselves in the planning process as stakeholders.
One of these is the King’s Cross Railway Lands Group (KXRLG),
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
Urban Redevelopment at King’s Cross, London
357
an umbrella organization with more than a hundred members (both
private members and organizations) which has been in existence for
over 20 years. The KXRLG has been the group most actively trying
to influence the planning and development process. Cally Rail Group
is another local “community group”, but in contrast to the KXRLG
it has a geographical basis, ie around Cally Road. Other stakeholder
groups are the King’s Cross Conservation Area Advisory Committee
(KXCAAC), Regents Canal Network, the Green Party and the Islington
Bangladeshi Association. These stakeholder groups also involve local
capital interests.
In turn, “community” is constituted by groups that cannot easily be
conceptualized along class lines. KXRLG or the local community do
not directly represent a class and have never articulated its demands
in terms of “class”. Yet in relation to Katznelson’s fourth layer of
class, collective action, the KXRLG arguably articulates interests and
organizes actions in contrast to the property owners and developers, in
other words, some kind of non-accumulators’ class interests. These
interests stand in antagonistic relations to the interests of property
owners on several aspects within the planned development. A more
class-sensitive articulation of these interests could therefore potentially
fracture “community” as constituted in King’s Cross.
These are aspects of the development process that contain clear class
effects. Three aspects will be closely looked at here: the amount of
office space; flexibility in the plans; and the appropriation of urban
environment as exchange value or use value.
Offices Space and Class
Argent has applied to construct buildings at up to 853,195 m2 of the
main site. As much as 455,510 m2 of this is regulated as “Business and
employment”, which is mainly office space. A study published by the
KXRLG and the University College of London in 1989 showed that
of the types of land use considered, office space was clearly the most
profitable (KXRLG 1989). The office market has more than recovered
after its crisis in the early 1990s, so it can be assumed that office space
is still today the most profitable type of construction (Hamnett 2005).
An architect from King’s Cross Central stated that the development of
office space would be the most profitable (interview). This is partly due
to the nature of the site, since the site is in a suitable office location
close to the city centre and close to an exceptional transport junction
(interview, Chief Executive, Argent). As mentioned above, attracting
offices to London is part of official policy, and the dominance of the
office-based financial sector in London’s employment and economic
projections has made the availability of suitable office accommodation
a critical issue (London Plan 2004:90). The development can in turn be
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
358
Antipode
seen as part of the strategy of strengthening London as an international
financial centre.
The dominance of office space within the development makes
class antagonisms visible. Stakeholder groups such as the Islington
Bangladeshi Association have raised the concern that the current
development would “not bring meaningful employment opportunities
to their young people—essentially, high level jobs would import labour
from other parts of labour leaving local people to—at best—fill low
skill positions” (Mace 2007:20). Two decades ago, dominated classes in
London normally had access to skilled industrial jobs (Hamnett 2005),
but the hegemonic shift in London where financial capital replaced
industrial capital has resulted in a highly segmented and polarized
labor market where locals will mostly be recruited into employment
such as cleaning and other lower service sector jobs. According to one
community activist with a minority background, this development is
welcome among local foreign-born “housewives” who do not always
speak English very well. They seek to occupy these lower service
sector jobs (interview, activist). These jobs stand in sharp contrast to
the high-wage financial sector jobs that are planned to be generated in
the office buildings. Lower service sector jobs dominated by immigrants
and temporary workers are notoriously difficult to organize (May et al
2007). A dominance of office space within the development is likely to
squeeze out “traditional” organized working class employment.1
In responses to a large consultation conducted by Camden in 2004,
the “common answer” was that “commercial office space should be
reduced as a proportion of the development” (Camden 2005:9). Also
the KXRLG has argued for a reduced scale of development, and in
order to:
obtain a more mixed, balanced and sustainable profile of land uses,
the office component is the obvious candidate for reduction. The more
business floor space provided, the less, within a finite total, is available
for other uses (e.g. housing, community, leisure and recreation etc) all
of which have commanded strong support and if anything most people
would like to see increased (KXRLG 2006a:3).
Flexibility in the Planning Process
The developer has never been committed to build a precise number of
buildings for particular uses, but an application is granted where they
might build up to a certain number of square meters for the different uses
(ARUP 2004). The plans are designed to allow the developer to change
plans according to market fluctuations, which local stakeholders argue
negates democratic oversight and accountability. Retaining flexibility
in the approved development plans is a central strategy for longterm profitability for Argent. As their Chief Executive explained, to
avoid bankruptcy in the event of a crisis, plans allow for a shift in
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
Urban Redevelopment at King’s Cross, London
359
building for different types of uses “because crashes in the [different
property] markets normally don’t come at the same time” (interview,
Chief Executive, Argent). And yet, according to a planning officer
from Camden, this flexibility cannot be used by planning authorities to
shift direction in the project according to changes in the social context
(interview, planning officer). The KXRGL held that by allowing for a
flexible process, the planning authorities were:
abrogating their responsibility to consider successive stages of
development in the light of developers’ performance in earlier stages,
changing government policy and changes in the London context
(KXRLG 2006a:4).
What is criticized is not flexibility as such, but that the flexibility
is controlled by Argent and not by the local planning authority. An
activist from the Cally Rail Group relates differently to “flexibility”:
“the problem with this scheme is that it’s both huge and amorphous”
(activist, quoted in Evening Standard 12 March 2007). Local
residents experienced Argent’s flexibility as uncertainty. The planning
process allows for flexibility in maximizing economic return for
property owners but little or no flexibility in allowing for changes
according to other types of concerns. This processual distinction
structures the planning process to the benefit of accumulating
interests.
Exchange Values and Use Values in the Urban Environment
Another distinction within the development is that between urban space
as exchange value and urban space as use value (Lefebvre 1973).2 In
other words, there is a difference between groups that appropriate space
for the purpose of accumulating capital and groups that appropriate
space as a place to live and work. This is manifested in the conflict
between shaping King’s Cross to maximize capital accumulation and
shaping it according to non-accumulative concerns. Stakeholder groups
campaigned strongly to mitigate the environmental effects of both the
development process and the final result.
Environmental concerns are points of contention between developers
and community groups, as the latter have argued that locals bear
excessive costs in the development process. Argent pushed for tall
buildings and privately owned streets, while KXRLG argued for the
need for a “satisfactory townscape”. The Cally Rail Group campaigned
against the noise from the building of the CTRL, arguing that the locals
“paid” undue costs for a development that eventually could price them
out of the area, bankrupt local shops, and “leave them what? Starbucks?”
(activist at King’s Cross Development Forum, 28 September 2006). The
community groups achieved some campaign victories on this issue, such
C 2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
360
Antipode
as a “mitigation package”, the installment of new windows and a stop
to the 24-hour work day (interview, activist).
The development is planned to necessitate the demolition of historical
buildings to accommodate the increased flow of traffic caused by the
redevelopment. Argent wanted to replace the Culross building and one
of the two Stanley buildings (Figure 1). An official from the Borough of
Camden explained that the buildings stop the flow between south and
north.
There will be 2 way buses and a tram through this house . . . They are
interesting buildings. But 450 taxis will drive through every hour, and
therefore we need a new road through one of the Stanley buildings.
And we got money for building the road now; therefore we need to
demolish the buildings (interview, planning officer).
The two buildings that must be demolished are also located south of
the canal, which is where the offices—the main source of accumulated
capital—will be built. The King’s Cross Conservation Area Advisory
Committee (KXCAAC) on the other hand, has fought for years to
protect these houses. KXCAAC argues that the houses are of great
historical significance because they are very early “workers’ dwellings”,
modern and special in their time. The developers aim to replace the
historical buildings with new fixed capital construction—ie offices and a
road—designed for continued accumulation. Yet the community groups
wished to retain the buildings for their non-accumulative use values.
The KXRLG argued that tall buildings and dense massing have adverse
consequences for “the setting and character of listed buildings and the
Conservation Areas”, and aimed for a “satisfactory townscape with
adequate permeability and open spaces” (KXRLG 2006a:4).
Agents and Class Interests
Although class identities are not articulated explicitly through the
conflict surrounding the King’s Cross development, distinct class
interests are embedded in the development process. Antagonistic lines
of division can be drawn between accumulating interests (appropriating
urban space as exchange value, some of which may benefit from
flexibility to accommodate market changes and aim to maximize office
space) and non-accumulating interests (appropriating space as use
value). But conflictual lines can also be drawn between intermediate
positions of accumulation. Distinctions can be made between agents
aiming to appropriate the urban space as exchange value. Argent is,
for example, owned by British Telecom’s Pension Scheme and has
committed itself to King’s Cross as a long-term investment, but this is
not the case for the two other owners, LCR and Exel. Argent’s main aim
is to circulate and accumulate capital through building fixed capital,
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
Urban Redevelopment at King’s Cross, London
361
Figure 1: Map of the contemporary site with the Stanley and Culross buildings marked
(source: produced by Kjell H Sjøstrøm)
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
362
Antipode
while LCR and Exel’s main aim is purely circulatory. Argent was not
originally the owner of the land under development, but has negotiated
the development with planning authorities on behalf of the ownership
vehicle. This management structure of the vehicle may have influenced
the development process towards longer-term concerns. According to an
official from the Borough of Camden, Exel and LCR shape the process
according to their need for short-term profit, while Argent’s interests
as future landlords generate differences in what type of development
process they promote. In one particular incident:
[the] LCR and Exel have wanted to reduce the amount of money
[the development vehicle] would give to Camden and Islington, for
example for building roads. We had a debate with Argent, and Argent
talked to the stakeholders [ie LCR and Exel], and Argent argued for
more money to Camden and Islington (interview, planning officer).
Another example of conflict within the same class is that local
businesses can benefit from increased capital inflows and economic
activity in the area, but also risk being squeezed out of the property
market. This was highlighted by a local magazine covering the
development in an article headlined “Independent business could stand
to benefit from the development—if they survive” (Cross Section
2006:27). For local residents, the changes in the property market have
been a central concern. According to a local resident and activist:
Property developers tell us that we are sitting on a gold mine. But that
depends on if you want to move or not. We would get something big
if we moved a long way out. But if you want to stay you earn nothing,
but you could sell and buy something similar or smaller (interview,
activist).
Changes in the property market also divide the non-accumulating
classes. Homeowners might get increased prices for their homes if they
sell, while increased housing rents might “gentrify away” those who do
not own property.
Table 1 summarizes the class interests of the main agents in the
conflict, in order to illustrate economic and class interests within the
King’s Cross development. The table aims to localize the functions
of the agents (following Edwards 1995), and relate their interests to
fixed capital (place) and circulating capital (space) (following Merrifield
1993).
Antagonism Versus Consensus in Planning
Community involvement has been the ideal throughout the King’s
Cross development. In addition to the official participatory process
managed by the Borough of Camden, there have been several rounds
of consultation and surveys organized by the Boroughs of Camden and
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
Urban Redevelopment at King’s Cross, London
363
Table 1: Agents, functions and class interests in the King’s Cross development
Agent
Function
Class interest
in built environment.
Fixed capital—place
Class interest
in general. Circulating
capital—space
Owned by BTPS’s
pension fund—defend
private sector workers’
pensions through
capitalist capital
accumulation
Capitalist company that
provides international
shipping and logistics
of documents and
freight
Consortium—established
to build the CTRL, earn
money and sell
everything off. Must
through a “secret deal”
also share some profit
with the state
Non-accumulators, ie
“labor”
Argent
Developer,
financer,
becoming
landlord
Long-term capital
investment. As
developer they hire
construction capital and
architects
Exel
Landlords
LCR
Landlords
Short-term capital
investment. Extract
land rent. In King’s
Cross only as
speculator
Short-term capital
investment. Extract
land rent. Also external
effect as owners of
nearby property
KXRLG
Community group
KXCAAC
KXBF
Promote
conservation of
historical
buildings
Local capital, LB
of Camden
organized
“Business
Coordinator”
Cally Rail
Group
Community/
residential project
“Use value”—in
Lefebvre’s terms.
Articulates a position of
the dominated classes.
With Harvey:
“consumption, personal
reproduction and
maybe expand”
“Use value” in Lefebvre’s
terms. Their interests
contrast with the
accumulators
Place to enhance
production and sell
products and services
“Use value”.
Homeowners might
benefit economically
None
Capital in general. Also
gaining from “trickle
down effect”, though
often limited
geographical
possibilities
None
Islington, academics, local residents, the King’s Cross Business Forum,
King’s Cross Development Forum and Argent itself. The King’s Cross
Development Forum was established so that community groups can join
in and “shape their future”. Camden wrote in 2004 that the community
involvement in relation to the King’s Cross Development should be
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
364
Antipode
“two-way, with all stakeholders both talking and listening” (Camden
and Islington 2004:9). According to a Camden planning officer speaking
at a meeting on 28 September 2006:
So far the Forum has remained a constant presence throughout the
process, has developed planning and other interests and knowledge,
and is an interesting arena for consultation and a range of local
communities available for discussion (Camden’s King’s Cross Team’s
Meeting Notes).
Yet the communication between developers, planners and stakeholders at a meeting in November 2006 was more in the form of
questions and answers than two-way dialogue (personal observation).
While questions were asked by the Forum’s members, the officers
responded and “explained” the reality of the project. For example, a
Forum participant asked whether a simpler version of the Section 106
agreement could be provided, as the current version is 546 pages long
and not readily accessible for community members. The answer was
simply that “no, everything in it is needed”. To another question on
whether more space could be provided for youth within the plans, the
answer was that there is sufficient space they can use, and this should
be discussed further later in the process. A third question on how locals
can use the University of Arts was also excluded as a matter for the
participatory planning process. The planning process had excluded these
and other issues from participatory involvement, often by appealing to
activists to understand the “realities” faced by the developers.
Communication seemed highly structured by the positions of the
“speaker” and lack of practical accountability. The community activists
also experienced the situation this way, and one said in an interview that
“today, there is a lot of participation on paper, so we have participated
for 20 years, but they don’t have to listen. They just have to show us
that they have read what we wrote”. He also said that communication is
an important democratic principle, but “as a principle for planning it is
just process and ignores the power issues in the status quo” (interview,
activist). Another conceded that there is some power in the King’s Cross
Development Forum, for example through the right to consultation on
all planning applications, but added that “when it comes to power, it’s
Camden and [the Chief Executive of Argent] that counts” (interview,
activist). A former Camden planner who is now an academic called the
public consultation a “rubber stamping exercise” (interview, researcher
and former planner).
The structure of public consultation appears to delimit participatory
influence. Community activists use the channels available, but are
still frustrated with the lack of influence on one hand, and the
legitimacy given to the development process by the fact that the
channels exist on the other. Although the locals have won some
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
Urban Redevelopment at King’s Cross, London
365
“victories” through campaigning, for the most past the premises seem
to be established beforehand and are not accessible for community
input. There seems to be a processual gap between consultation
and influence, which can also be discerned within planning theory’s
preoccupation with “communication” and a lack of recognition of
economic antagonisms. The developers considered the participation as
interference by individuals, rather than a representation of community
interests. This is indicated by a statement from Argent’s Chief Executive:
We must work hard to protect our objectives from a tiny minority of
obsessed people. They’re compulsive and have a disorder syndrome.
They don’t like the private sector, or the public sector. They don’t like
the establishment . . . There is a dozen, bright people who frustrate us
(interview).
Another way of looking at KXRLG is as a well-organized political body
which has been around for 20 years, and which has organized hundreds
of members and contains a lot of expertise. The fact that the developer
Argent, represented here by its Chief Executive, has such a view on the
“others participants” in the communicative planning process indicates
how the communicative planning process functions in practice.
The King’s Cross Business Forum is operative to promote the interests
of local business interests, supported by the London Development
Agency, and is recognized in the consultation process as a legitimate
actor. For instance, when a phone service was set up in order to put
local workers, stakeholders and shop owners in touch with another so
that locals might get local jobs, this was done under the Business Forum
rather than the Development Forum. The consultation process can be
seen as an articulation of class interests where business interests are
articulated as such, while labor interests are embedded in the classambiguous category of “community”. Instead of class issues, opposing
interests are linked to the notion of “community”. Cally Rail Group
defines itself as an “unfunded community group formed nearly twelve
years ago” (Cally Rail Group 2006:8). KXRLG defines itself as a
“local group made up of community groups and individuals living and
working in Camden and Islington” (KXRLG 2006b:12). King’s Cross
Business Forum “aims to draw the local business community together
acting as a voice for business through our activities” (Camden 2006:21).
Argent argues that “KXC [King’s Cross Central] will deliver benefits to
existing local communities” (Argent St George 2001:23). And finally,
the Borough of Camden argues that the King’s Cross Development
Forum is “run by [Camden] on behalf of the local communities”.
The case of King’s Cross is a materialization of the conflict
between the theory of consensus and an experience of antagonism.
There are distinct class conflicts within the development process that
structure the communicative process according to the interests of capital
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
366
Antipode
accumulation. These conflicts can be seen as existing on an abstract
structural level (Katznelson’s first layer of class), manifested as power
asymmetries in the planning process (second layer), experienced as clear
antagonistic interests (third layer), and practiced through community
activism and campaigning (fourth layer). The development and its
planning process have clear class effects, but structure these as a sort
of friction between participants in the consultations and the “realities”
faced by the development. Class conflicts are obscured in the process,
and accommodating these interests is precluded from participatory
influence by the structure of communicative planning.
Conclusion
We initially made the claim that critiques of the communicative turn
in planning did not properly account for class antagonisms, and
that conceptualizations should be developed to understand how class
antagonisms structure planning processes. These conceptualizations
should take as their point of departure that different groups have
antagonistic relations within processes of capital accumulation, and
that these antagonisms cannot be overcome merely through proper
communication. A class-sensitive analysis of a development project
should begin with a mapping of the class interests of different groups,
which opens up an understanding of how these interests structure the
planning process itself. We argued for a theory of how class interests are
layered and thereby complexly articulated in actual conflicts. In King’s
Cross we looked at three aspects of the planning process to exemplify the
mechanisms by which a planning process is structured towards particular
class interests. We looked at the amount of office space, flexibility in the
plans, and the appropriation of the urban environment as exchange or use
value. These aspects were external to the communicative process, which
functioned largely through informing citizens of plans already made. In
turn, class interests structured the development project in much more
fundamental ways than the communicative process. We take this as
empirical support of the need for what might be called class-sensitive
planning theory and class-sensitive politics in planning practice.
With issues of class and economic antagonisms virtually absent from
the discourse on the King’s Cross project, the opposition groups to
the project are articulated as “community groups”, a class-ambiguous
category. On the other hand, business interests are articulated as
such, for example through the King’s Cross Business Group. There
is little or no antagonistic relation between these two categories of
interests, since “community” also involves local business. The political
effect of this discourse is that no antagonistic relations are articulated
against business/capital interests, which is in line with the neoliberal
dogma that “what is good for business is good for everyone”. It can
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
Urban Redevelopment at King’s Cross, London
367
be hypothesized that “community” is only one of a range of classambiguous categories that have become widespread lately because
they serve neoliberal discourses that promote economic rationality
rather than economic antagonisms in the governance of society. If
correct, this observation should imply a more critical engagement with
central concepts of communicative planning theory and practice. As our
mapping of class interests in an urban redevelopment project shows, the
planning discourse has clear class effects.
Three strategies for reinserting class into planning theory and practice
can be proposed. The first strategy is the acknowledgement that
capitalism is based on economic antagonisms. When identifying “needs”
in planning theory or practice, it is important to ask, whose needs? In
contrast to contemporary assumptions where “communities” are the
subjects and where “consensus” is an ideal (as in the King’s Cross
Development), we would argue that one should recognize and consider
antagonisms like class.
The second strategy is to take into account the dialectics and
interdependence between different social, economic and political
spheres. This involves the acknowledgement that economic rationality
is embedded in these spheres and that (at least a theoretical) coherence
with social and political spheres should be aimed for. Marcuse called
the contemporary lack of this acknowledgement the “problem with
pragmatism” (Marcuse 2007). In King’s Cross, for example, it is obvious
that the problem of unemployment arises as an effect of broader
socio-economic and political processes, and that housing issues are
interdependent with overarching processes of law, the state and the
economy. It follows that the point of departure for planning must be
beyond particular projects; it must be conceived as a dialectic relation
with general tendencies in society.
The third strategy is then to take standpoints in antagonisms like class.
A socially just policy on this is to take a standpoint for the dominated
classes. Gunder (2003) takes the normative standpoint that one should
aim to plan “for the joy of the Others’ desire”, and contemporary
planning discourses make normative standpoints for “communities” and
“investment climates”. In the conflict surrounding the King’s Cross
development, initiatives were taken to promote local business and
communities, but not the dominated classes. These examples show that
standpoints are prevalent in planning, but economic antagonisms are
currently not considered bases for legitimate standpoints. The planning
process at King’s Cross or the planning status quo as such are in effect
not any less political than a standpoint for the dominated classes, they are
just favoring different classes. Class-sensitive planning would involve
turning planning theory and practice towards a concern for how urban
development projects can promote consciousness around social issues
and (more) equal distributions of economic value.
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
368
Antipode
Acknowledgements
The Radical Geography Group in Bergen, particularly Kari Anne Drangsland, provides
spaces for thinking critically about geography. Judith Allen, Michael Edwards, Arild
Holt-Jensen and Peter Marcuse helped shape the ideas. Guy Baeten, Noel Castree and
three anonymous reviewers provided constructive comments that significantly improved
a late version of this paper.
Endnotes
1
This opens the arena for two very different classes: the (often foreign-born) cleaners
and the (also often foreign-born) financial sector middle class, and neither are likely to
organize.
2
Lefebvre treats these categories as ways of relating to space, which diverges from
Marx’s use which describes forms of the commodity.
References
Allen J (1986) Smoke over the Winter Palace—the politics of resistance and London’s
community areas. Occasional Papers - University of Westminster 1(4):72
Allmendinger P and Tewdwr-Jones M (2002) The communicative turn in urban planning:
Unravelling paradigmatic, imperialistic and moralistic dimensions. Space and Polity
6(1):5–24
Amdam J and Veggeland N (1998) Teorier om Samfunnsplanlegging. Oslo:
Universitetsforlaget
Argent St George (2001) Parameters for Regeneration. Work in Progress for King’s
Cross Central. London: Argent
ARUP (2004) King’s Cross Central—Regeneration Strategy. London: Argent St George,
LCR, Exel
Brenner N (2004) New State Spaces: Urban Governance and the Rescaling of Statehood.
Oxford: Oxford University Press
Cally Rail Group (2006) Response to Argent King’s Cross Revised Outline Planning
Applications for King’s Cross Central in the London Boroughs of Camden and
Islington. London: Cally Rail Group
Camden LBo (2001) Camden’s Community Strategy. London: London Borough of
Camden
Camden LBo (2005) King’s Cross Central Development—Initial Survey Of Consultation
Results. London: London Borough of Camden
Camden LBo (2006) Replacement Unitary Development Plan. London: London
Borough of Camden
Camden LBo and Islington LBo (2004) King’s Cross Opportunity Area. Planning &
Development Brief . London: London Borough of Camden
Cerny P (1995) Globalization and the changing logic of collective action. International
Organization 49(4):595–625
Cross Section (2006) Profit and loss. September
DETR (1998) Community-based regeneration initiatives: A working paper. Department
of the Environment, Transport and the Regions, London
Edwards M (1995) Agents and functions in urban development: Frameworks for
analysis. Cartas Urbanas 4:26–39
Edwards M, MacDonald K, Newman P and Thornley A (1992) A vision for London. In
Thornley A (ed) The crisis of London (pp 185–201). London: Routledge
Fainstein S (2000) New directions in planning theory. Urban Affairs Review 35(4):451–
478
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
Urban Redevelopment at King’s Cross, London
369
Fine J (2005) Community unions and the revival of the American labor movement.
Politics & Society 33(1):153–199
Flyvbjerg B (1998) Rationality and Power: Democracy in Practice. Chicago: The
University of Chicago Press
Flyvbjerg B and Petersen V (1983) Planning Theory—Theoretical Considerations on
the Analysis of Public Policy and Planning. Aalborg: Aalborg University Press
Gibson-Graham J K (2006) The End of Capitalism (As We Knew It). Minneapolis:
University of Minnesota Press
Gunder M (2003) Passionate planning for the others’ desire: An agonistic response to
the dark side of planning. Progress in Planning 60:235–319
Haarstad H (2007) Collective political subjectivity and the problem of scale.
Contemporary Politics 13(1):57–74
Habermas J (1993) Justification and Application—Remarks on Discourse Ethic.
London: MIT Press
Hamnett C (2005) Unequal City—London in the Global Arena. London: Routledge
Harvey D (1978) Labor, capital, and class struggle around the built environment in
advanced capitalist societies. In K R Cox (ed) Urbanization and Conflict in Market
Societies (pp 9–37). London: Methuen & Co
Harvey D (1985) The Urbanization of Capital. Oxford: Basil Blackwell
Harvey D (1989) The Condition of Postmodernity: An Enquiry Into the Origins of
Cultural Change. Oxford: Basil Blackwell
Harvey D (1999) The Limits to Capital. London: Verso
Harvey D (2005) A Brief History of Neoliberalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press
Healey P (1996) Planning theory debate: The communicative turn in planning theory. In
S Campbell and S Fainstein (eds) Readings in planning theory (pp 234–257). Oxford:
Blackwell
Healey P (1999) Institutionalist analysis, communicative planning and shaping places.
Journal of Planning Education and Research 19(19):111–121
Jessop B (1994) Post-Fordism and the state. In A Amin (ed) Post-Fordism: A Reader
(pp 251–279). Oxford: Blackwell
Jones M and Ward K (2002) Excavating the logic of British urban policy: Neoliberalism
as the “crisis of crisis-management”. In N Brenner and N Theodore (eds) Spaces
of Neoliberalism—Urban Restructuring in North America and Western Europe
(pp 126–147). Oxford: Blackwell
Katznelson I (1993) Marxism and the City. Oxford: Clarendon Press
Knox P and Pinch S (2006) Urban Social Geography—An Introduction. Essex: Pearson
KXRLG (1989) The King’s Cross Development—People or Profit? London: King’s
Cross Railway Lands Community Development Group
KXRLG (2006a) Dear Mr Prescott. Letter, 29 March. King’s Cross Railway Lands
Group
KXRLG (2006b) Network—The Quarterly Journal of the Kings Cross Railway Lands
Group. London: Kings Cross Railway Lands Group
Lash S and Urry J (1987) The End of Organized Capitalism. Cambridge: Polity Press
Lefebvre H (1973) Det Bymæssige Rums Produktionsproces. Arkitekturteoretisk
kompendierække. Aarhus: Aarhus Universitetet
Lefebvre H (1991) The Production of Space. Oxford: Blackwell
London Plan (2004) The London Plan. Spatial Development Strategy for Greater
London. London: Mayor of London
Mace A (2007) “Making the hard-to-reach harder to reach. The role of statements of
community involvement in planning King’s Cross.” Unpublished manuscript
Marcuse P (2007) “Socialism in the ideologies of urban planning.” Unpublished
manuscript
Marx K (1990) Capital Volume I. London: Penguin
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation
370
Antipode
May J, Wills J, Datta K, Evans Y, Herbert J and McIlwaine C (2007) Keeping London
working: Global cities, the British state and London’s new migrant division of labour.
Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers 32(2):151–167
Merrifield A (1993) Place and space: A Lefebvrian reconciliation. Transactions of the
Institute of British Geographers 18(4):516–531
Naustadalslid J (1991) Kommunal Styring—Innføring i Kommunalkunnskap Frå ein
Planleggingssynstad. Oslo: Det Norske Samlaget
ODPM (2004) Planning Policy Statement 12—Local Developments Frameworks.
London: Office of the Deputy Prime Minister
Peck J and Tickell A (2003) Searching for a new institutional fix: The after-Fordist crisis
and the global-local disorder. In A Amin (ed) Post-Fordism: A Reader (pp 280–315).
Oxford: Blackwell
Short J (1996) The Urban Order. Malden, MA: Blackwell
Skjeggedal T (2005) Ambitions and realities in Norwegian regional planning. European
Planning Studies 13(5):731–748
Smith N (1991) Uneven Development—Nature, Capital and the Production of Space.
Oxford: Basil Blackwell
Swyngedouw E (2004) Globalisation or ‘glocalisation’? Networks, territories and
rescaling. Cambridge Review of International Affairs 17(1):25–48
Tewdwr-Jones M, Morphet J and Allmendinger P (2006) The contested strategies of
local governance: Community strategies, development plans, and local government
modernisation. Environment and Planning A 38(3):533–551
Toulouse C (1991) Thatcherism, class politics, and urban development in London.
Critical Sociology 18(1):55–76
Wills J (2001) Community unionism and trade union renewal in the UK: Moving
beyond the fragments at last? Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers
26(4):465–483
Yiftachel O and Huxley M (2000) Debating dominance and relevance: Notes on
the “communicative turn” in planning theory. International Journal of Urban and
Regional Research 24(4):907–913
C
2009 The Authors
C 2009 Editorial Board of Antipode.
Journal compilation